A designer in a lecture stated that, in addition to
the obvious forces that influence a design – the needs of users, the strength
of materials, the costs of production – there exist less obvious ethical ones
that also affect design decisions. He then urged us to pay more attention to
the ethical effects of our designed world.
While we often think of
ethics applying to our individual actions, our notions of right and wrong or
good and bad relate just as much to the larger economic and political forces
that shape and constrain the designed world in which we live. In that sense, designers
literally give physical form to the public policies that politicians have put
in place, even though many designers rarely think of what we do in this way. We
tend to judge a design according to its aesthetics and pragmatics: does it look
good, function well, and meet our budget? But we can also assess a design in
terms of the ethics of the codes and regulations, taxes and fees, and incentives
and inducements that influenced the designer’s decisions and that defined the
context within which the design evolved.
We may not talk as much
about the latter because public policies can sometimes seem more like a force
of nature, something beyond our control, but those policies actually arise out
of a kind of design thinking. As designers do every day, elected officials
devise policies in order to achieve a desired end or to address an unmet need.
And the designed products and environments that literally embed those policies
in their form, function, and material, provide one of the best ways of judging
the merit of these policies. A design doesn’t have to have a reflective surface
in order to offer us a mirror of what we value as individuals and as a
political and economic community.
When we look in that
mirror, we see a mixture of carrots and sticks. The social contract of most
modern countries accepts the use of incentives as well as prohibitions and
penalties in order to achieve what at least those in power at any given moment
conceive of as good or bad. And the differing degree to which those in power
use carrots or sticks depends upon their approach to ethics. Those who favor
incentivizing good behavior, for example, implicitly embrace virtue ethics. If
we believe almost all people have the capacity to be virtuous – honest, fair,
prudent, and so on – then incentivizing people with economic carrots makes
total sense.
Meanwhile, decision-makers
who have a less sanguine view of human virtue may resort more to the use of sticks.
Utilitarian ethics often underpins public policies that use the “stick” of
taxation or fees. Such policies rarely prohibit certain behaviors or decisions,
but instead focus on spreading resources in order to benefit the greatest
number and on nudging people toward seeing their own good in the common good.
Likewise, the categorical
imperatives of Kant’s ethics, based on his belief that there exist absolute and
universal rights and wrongs, can lead politicians to enact laws that wield a
big stick, proscribing certain behaviors or prohibiting the use of certain
substances or materials. Drawing such a clear line between the legal and
illegal echoes the Kantian advice to not do anything that we wouldn’t accept if
universally applied.
Designers do not just respond
to these carrots and sticks; we become agents in their enactment through what
we design. And the more we attend to the ethics of design, the more conscious
we will be of the values our work promotes.
Dear Prof I am searching for your book:
ReplyDeleteEthics for Architects: 50 Dilemmas of Professional Practice
if it is available e-book
I would be greatfull if you could send it to me by email:
hind_50abde@yahoo.com
http://www.hindamkh.blogspot.com
(PhD student) and Lecturer "DAU University, Saudi Arabia)
Thanks
Dear Hind Abdel Moneim Khogali,
DeleteMy book, Ethics for Architects, can be ordered for shipment to Saudi Arabia from: www.amazon.com/Ethics-Architects-Dilemmas-Professional-Architecture/dp/1568989466/ref=sr_1_1?s=books&ie=UTF8&qid=1335642167&sr=1-1