After a lecture on sustainability, in which the
lecturer spoke about the much greater energy efficiency of buildings and
vehicles in recent decades, a student asked why we continue to consume energy
at an ever-greater rate even as we have become more efficient in doing so and
if that meant that energy efficiency worked against the goal of reducing energy
consumption.
The British economist
William Stanley Jevons observed, in the mid-19th Century, that with
the greater efficiency in the use of coal, the consumption of coal increased at
a greater rate, leading to the paradox that efficiency can increase rather than
decrease the use of a resource. We can easily see why Jevons paradox can occur.
Greater efficiency in the use of a resource can reduce its price, which prompts
more consumption, and it can also increase economic growth, which also fuels
greater use as more people can afford to do so. Jevons argued that because of
this paradox, we couldn’t rely only on improvements in efficiency to reduce
consumption of a fuel source like coal.
This raises a fundamental
ethical issue, as well as an environmental one. In an era in which designers
have worked very hard to increase the efficiency of energy consuming entities
like buildings and vehicles, with the goal of reducing the use of finite
supplies of fossil fuel, Jevons paradox poses a particularly challenging
problem. Jevons did not say that we should, as a result of his paradox, ignore
efficiency. He simply said that we cannot depend upon it alone and that other
non-technological changes need to happen as well if we want to reduce
consumption.
Some have argued that
public policies can counter the paradoxical effects of greater efficiency. We
can add a tax on the resource, place quotas on its use, or regulate its
availability to keep the price high, even as the efficiency of its use
increases. Such tactics, though, have proven to be hard to sell politically,
striking some as “social engineering” by tampering with the way in which the
marketplace innovates to increase the efficiency and reduce the cost of things.
That the marketplace is itself a kind of social engineering doesn’t get
discussed often enough, but so be it. We seem driven, at least in modern, technological
societies, to increase consumption of resources until they become scarce (or damaging)
enough that we can no longer afford them or have them available in enough
quantity.
Ethics, though, offers
another way of looking at this paradox. One of the primary divisions between
ancient and modern ethics has to do with being versus doing. The ancients focused
on what it meant to be a good person or on the nature of a good society, while
we moderns have tended to dwell, instead, on what it means to do the right
thing regardless of or because of its consequences. Jevons paradox occurs when
we only focus on “doing.” And Jevons seemed to acknowledge that when he said
that making a process more efficient alone
would not reduce consumption. Doing the right thing also depends upon our
being a good person and our living in a good society.
The Stoic philosophers,
for example, argued that our freedom and happiness comes not from how much we
have, but rather from how much we can do without. This may sound at odds with our
consumer-oriented culture, but it simply extends to human behavior the same ethic
designers embrace when making things more efficient. The real paradox in Jevons
observation has to do with the modern disconnect between what we do and who we
are.